Quantcast
Channel: pseudoerasmus
Viewing all articles
Browse latest Browse all 102

Der Todd des Euro

$
0
0

Part 1. The French anthropologist-demographer Emmanuel Todd, who is becoming increasingly fashionable in the Anglosphere, is also a scathing critic of the euro. I examine his “anthropological” views of Germany and the euro, which I also contrast with those of Michael Pettis


(1)

The other day I stumbled upon this innocently admiring blogpost on Emmanuel Todd which contained a video of him speaking in English about France and the euro. The clip is an excerpt of a panel discussion organised by Harper’s magazine (partial transcript).

In the Harper’s video Todd mostly wears his demographer’s hat and the anthropologist doppelgänger that is conspicuous in his French appearances is rather restrained. Around 18:20 he argues that the euro cannot work, in part, because the French population is much younger than Germany’s. There’s some truth in this, because a younger population may prefer more inflation and an older one may prefer more surpluses. But, arguably, Germany with its grumpy old people is more youth-friendly when it comes to employment policies, than France.

Between 2:30 and 3:30, Todd mentions that France had traditionally relied on currency devaluation in times of recession in order to achieve full employment and avoid fiscal austerity. That’s precisely what Eurozone countries can’t do today. That’s mentioned almost in passing, but it’s a key element of Todd’s views of Germany and the euro. He believes that for Germany “competitive disinflation is a nationalist strategy“, because German industry has achieved international competitiveness by restraining growth of labour costs at the expense of its European partners. But when it comes specifically to competing for a share of the export pie, there is no difference between Germany’s “internal devaluation” and the standard “external devaluation” that Todd would like France to be able to do. They are both competitive devaluations !

(2)

A prominent French critic of the euro ubiquitous in the French media, Todd is an anthropologist-demographer who has documented the family structures of the world and their relation to political systems and ideologies. His very best book, L’invention de l’Europe, which has yet to be translated into English, reinterprets the whole of European history in terms of diverse family systems. (See Craig Willy’s masterly summary of the book.)

For anyone who follows France, Todd’s views of the euro should be familiar — the European situation cannot be analysed just economically, it requires the insight of the historian-demographer-anthropologist ; the euro is a vehicle for German domination ; the survival of the euro would imply the death of democracy ; François Hollande is not president of France but der deutsche Vizekanzler, etc. And he’s been saying such things for some time now.

Although he’s a brilliant polemicist who runs circles around his debate opponents, his rhetoric can be pretty crude and shrill, and he’s been criticised for “Germanophobia” (also here). In a French TV panel discussion, he argued, in a few years there may be “no French industry worthy of its name”, and the “attitude of the German bosses behind Angela Merkel” is to engineer the “elimination of Germany’s competitors”. When the co-panelist Ulrike Guérot protested that Germany is today a liberal pluralistic society, Todd replied, yes, we all know about the many Germanies but in the end the illiberal, authoritarian one always wins ! In the Harper’s transcript of its panel discussion, Todd said,

The idea was to make Germany a European country. What we have instead is Europe as a German power zone. It’s all very peaceful. It’s like a peaceful parody of the past, but it’s the same past.

In this French TV debate with Marine Le Pen nodding across from him, Todd went all out (after 13:00) :

We speak of protectionism for Europe. Why don’t the Germans favour protectionism for Europe ? And why are the Germans so-called “free-traders” ? It’s not like the English. They are true free-traders, they committed suicide for free trade, they sacrified their industry for free trade…. The Germans are different…. And I repeat [tone of sarcastic pro forma gratitude] it’s an admirable culture, we owe them [this and that] But there is, in the German culture, a different conception of the nation and national solidarity. What does that mean ? If you were to implement in France a free trade regime, the French, the really nice universalists that we are, woud buy any old car, according to price and quality. Moreover we would buy foreign just because it’s nice to have foreign things. But that is not [waving his finger] German culture. It’s a culture of controlling its neighbours… The Germans hunt in packs… It’s a cultural thing. It’s not pretty, it’s very unpleasant for our French conception of the universal man. [interruption] But that’s what’s happening ! The truth is, the German citizen, not always, but statistically, will buy German…

The core problem, in Todd’s eyes, is a deep-seated chauvinistic quest across the Rhine for economic hegemony. His vision of the “German problem” is rather reminiscent of the one identified by Clyde Prestowitz in the 1980s, a jeremiad of Japanese economic hegemony. It’s not the conventional narrative of low-wage countries eating away at the industrial base of the rich economies. In an interview in Marianne, Todd compared Germany with China :

But the policy carried out by Germany in Europe, or by China in Asia, shows that globalisation does not, uniquely or even principally, pit the emerging markets against the developed countries. Globalisation leads to confrontation between neighbours. When the Germans conduct a policy of wage reduction in order to lower labour costs, the impact is non-existent on the Chinese economy, but is considerable for its partners in the Euro zone. When the Chinese manipulate the yuan, it’s against Thailand, Indonesia or Brazil, its competitors in low-wage labour. What we notice is a tendency of the emerging markets to fight amongst themselves and the developed countries to exterminate one another industrially, with the objective of being the last to go down with the ship. This mechanism has turned the Euro zone into a trap, with Germany, whose economy is the most powerful,  in the role of fox in the henhouse.

Since Todd is quite arrogant and condescending about having a deeper “anthropological” perspective on the European Union than other commentators, it’s worth exploring what that is exactly.

(3)

According to himself, much of Todd’s analysis is a direct implication of his academic work. In Willy’s summary of Todd, the “stem family” that is characteristic of Germany is

…authoritarian and inegalitarian. Several generations may live under one roof, notably the first-born, who will inherit the entirety of property and family headship (and thus perpetuate the family line).

In L’origine des systèmes familiaux, Todd’s magnum opus (also yet untranslated), the “stem family combines authority and inequality, essential bureaucratic values, and its ideal of continuity was one of the roads toward the modern state”. This implies :

Whether on the left, on the right or in the centre, German ideological forces always end up creating enormous agglomeration machines [“vastes machines intégratrices”]. The mass political parties — SDP, the Centre, NSDAP — are surrounded by a constellation of professional or cultural satellite organisations. Spontaneously, party loyalty produces in Germany vertically integrated “subsocieties” which realise, within the context of modern society and economy, the ideal of the “estates” system of the Ancien Régime. The social-democratic estate of workers, the Christian democratic estate of Catholics, the Nazi order of Protestant middle classes in 1930. [From L’invention de l’Europe, my translation.]

The book which discusses some actual economics is the untranslated L’illusion économique. It argues that globalisation is defined by the interaction of two opposite yet complementary systems of capitalism — the Anglo-American or individualistic capitalism ; and the “integrated” capitalism exemplified by Germany and Japan. (The book also contains a whole chapter bitching about the lack of anthropological perspectives in economic analysis.)

I paraphrase Todd : Anglo-Saxon capitalism is focused on short-term profits and consumption, resulting in, simultaneously, high turnover amongst workers, frequent creative destruction of businesses, a low savings rate and high external deficits. This system requires for its perpetuation the existence of its “double negative”, the “integrated capitalism” of Germany and Japan where

…the true objective of the firm is not the optimisation of profit, the satisfaction of the shareholder, but the conquest of market shares, through the perfection and expansion of production. From an ideological point of view, the producer is king : the attention to technological progress and the training of labour are intensive. You have to excel in quality. The consumer is but a modest subject and one is tempted to assert that the deep logic of the system is to treat consumption as a necessary evil…

Germany and Japan are viscerally incapable of consuming the totality of goods produced by their industrial systems. Like Anglo-Saxon capitalism, the Germano-Nippon type is simultaneously coherent and unbalanced. Exports are a condition of survival, which presuppose the existence of its double negative, the capitalism of the importers.

Much of the above synthesises two strands of academic thought which were a vivid part of the Zeitgeist in the 1980s and 1990s : the “Asian economic model” as exposited in Chalmers Johnson’s MITI and the Japanese Miracle or Alice Amsden’s Rise of the Rest : Challenges to the West from the Late Industrialisers ; as well as Michel Albert‘s “capitalisme rhénan” or “Rhenish capitalism”, the Eurocentric variant of the “Asian model” argued in Capitalism vs Capitalism (which was more widely read in France than elsewhere). Both strands were ultimately rooted in older alternatives to British classical economics — the American institutional economics associated with Thorstein Veblen (and later with John Kenneth Galbraith) and the German historical school of economics. The ultimate genealogy for both might be the German Friedrich List (who heavily influenced Japanese planners in the 1880s and 1890s). In the 1990s, however, much of that fashion receded with Japanese stagnation, the Asian financial crisis of 1997-98, high unemployment in the “big” economies of Europe, and American economic boom.

Todd’s own idiosyncratic twist is the very Gallic anthropologisation of that “duality of global capitalism” :

Most of the significant traits of individualistic capitalism can be reduced to the fundamental values of the absolute nuclear family, which favour emancipation and mobility of individuals. At the most general level, the values of the nuclear family determine a preference for the short term, what Anglo-Saxon authors call “short-termism”. The nuclear family system does not have a lineage plan, it is defined by a continuous separation between generations [“ruptures générationnelles successives”]. Children, once adults, must leave [the family], begin a new story. The discontinuities which characterise the Anglo-Saxon world, whether it be the mobility of capital or of labour, are but the reflexion of the customs favouring mobility in general…

The long-term outlook of “integrated” capitalism, favouring technological research, investment, training of personnel and job stability within the firm — symmetrically [i.e., as a parallel with Anglo-Saxon capitalism] finds its source in the values of continuity which define the stem family. Strong parental authority, inequality of inheritance, existed only to assure the perpetuation of the lineage. The continuity of the past, noble or peasant, becomes the continuity of the firm and its projects.

The strong propensity to save and invest which characterise “stem capitalism” is but a particular economic manifestation accounting for this relationship with time. To save, to invest, is to project oneself into the future. Conversely, consumption, engrossed in the present, and escape into debt reflect, in a logically complementary manner, the mental universe of the nuclear family.

[Paraphrase : the differences between “nuclear” capitalism and “stem” capitalism could not be made manifest without globalisation.]

It’s because they can export that Japan and Germany have expressed their tendency to underconsumption ; it’s because they can import that the United States has expressed its tendency to overconsumption. Openness has not led to a convergence of systems but to their differentiation. Economic history does not follow La Fontaine’s fable : the ant (stem) lends to the cricket (absolute nuclear) what it needs — cars, television sets, computers — in order to continuing singing.

I think the above is very silly. Although I do agree there are cultural differences between “individualism” and “collectivism”, nevertheless Todd’s derivation of these traits from family structures is little more than literary semiotics. That’s perhaps why he can occasionally babble about “killing God” or “killing the father” (à la Freud) in La troisième planète (which has been translated into English as Explanation of Ideology).

The mapping of those individualist/collectivist traits to the macroeconomic aggregates we see today is all wrong. Todd wants to “essentialise” the macro conditions that have only existed since the late 1970s, but those are not deep-seated historical truths at all or manifestations of deep culture. They are instead highly contingent facts of politics and economics. England had been the premier surplus-savings exporter of the 19th century, contrary to everything Todd says. At the same time, the United States, despite its individualistic ethos that supposedly champions the consumer, nonetheless created an utterly producer-dominated system of quasi-monopolistic industrial trusts protected by tariffs. And it’s especially clear in retrospect that Japan and the East Asian tigers were high-surplus countries after 1945 only because the United States played along as part of the Cold War strategy of building up its allies.

In fact, Todd’s “essentialisation” of current account balances can easily be disproved by the record of the last 140 years (5-year moving averages of current account balances as % of GDP) :

current account balance long duree

South Korea, another “stem capitalism” country in Todd’s estimation, had actually been riddled with current account deficits before the 2000s when it decided to change policy as a result of the Asian financial crisis.

Todd’s “anthropological determinism” is misplaced. His vision of the hierarchical authoritarian German culture is much more geared toward explaining the German past, than the common thread running through both that past and the current realities of the Federal Republic. I’m not opposed to anthropological determinism  per se. There are indeed deep cultural differences between Germany (or northern Europe) and the rest of Europe that affect the euro, but there is a better “anthropological” angle than the one Todd pushes. (*)

(4)

Todd’s “anthropological” view of global balances clashes fundamentally with that aired by Michael Pettis, author of The Great Rebalancing, who is has become for the 2010s what Nouriel Roubini had been in 1998-2008. Pettis is not the Roubini of Dr. Doom, but another who popularly expounds a view of the world economy as a closed system in which current account imbalances play a commanding role. The drumbeat that Pettis constantly beats is that government policy, not the primordially thrifty behaviour of Chinese and German households, is the cause of global imbalances.

Germany’s export of its excess national savings (i.e., not needed for domestic purposes ) did help finance the debt binge in the crisis countries of Europe and, in the view of many, Germany’s large current account surpluses are inconsistent with economic recovery in the Eurozone. From Pettis’s article cited above :

In the 1990s Germany could be described as saving too little. It often ran current account deficits during the decade, which means that the country imported capital to fund domestic investment. A country’s current account deficit is simply the difference between how much it invests and how much it saves, and Germans in the 1990s did not always save enough to fund local investment.

But this changed in the first years of the last decade. An agreement among labor unions, businesses and the government to restrain wage growth in Germany (which dropped from 3.2 percent in the decade before 2000 to 1.1 percent in the decade after) caused the household income share of GDP to drop and, with it, the household consumption share. Because the relative decline in German household consumption powered a relative decline in overall German consumption, German saving rates automatically rose.

Notice that German savings rate did not rise because German households decided that they should prepare for a difficult future in the eurozone by saving more. German household preferences had almost nothing to do with it. The German savings rate rose because policies aimed at restraining wage growth and generating employment at home reduced household consumption as a share of GDP.

As national saving soared, the German economy shifted from not having enough savings to cover domestic investment needs to having, after 2001, such high savings that not only could it finance all of its domestic investment needs but it had to invest abroad by exporting large and growing amounts of savings. As it did so its current account surplus soared, to 7.5 percent of GDP in 2007. Martin Wolf, in an excellent Financial Times article on Wednesday on the subject, points out that

“between 2000 and 2007, Germany’s current account balance moved from a deficit of 1.7 per cent of gross domestic product to a surplus of 7.5 per cent. Meanwhile, offsetting deficits emerged elsewhere in the eurozone. By 2007, the current account deficit was 15 per cent of GDP in Greece, 10 per cent in Portugal and Spain, and 5 per cent in Ireland.”

( Pettis is a little too lenient on the PIGS countries. Leniency is perhaps deserved for Ireland and Spain, whose governments were not fiscally reckless as their economies were growing in the 2000s, although their fiscal policies might have been even tighter given all the capital inflows ; and it was their private sector which absorbed their countries’ current account deficits. But in Portugal and especially Greece, it was government budget deficits which fuelled the current account deficits. That was not “inevitable”. )

Two things to keep in mind, which are tautologies I won’t bother explaining : (a) trade surplus/deficit (more precisely, current account surplus/deficit) is the mirror reflexion of the national savings surplus/deficit, or the excess over GDP of total domestic spending by consumers, businesses and the public ; and (b) national savings is not the same thing as household savings. Changes in national savings can be caused by shifts in the behaviour of governments and businesses, not merely through the stirrings in the bosom of the thrifty burgher. So while it’s true that the Germans are thriftier than many of their neighbours,

personal_savings

the German household savings rate has changed relatively little, in comparison with the country’s current account balance :

german_current_account

So Germany as a country is not, contra Todd, some intrinsically surplus-producing economy. Still less was the turn from deficit to surplus in Germany’s current account an element of some mercantilist-hegemonist export strategy by the Reich to “exterminate” its neighbours economically, as Todd would have it. Unlike China’s current account balances, Germany’s are a by-product of domestic developments, and in fact I will argue — contra Pettis — the external surpluses were not even really intended at a policy level.

I repeat, I do believe there are deeper “anthropological” reasons for Germany’s  economic behaviour. I only reject Todd’s traditional family structure as the explanation. But part 2 discusses roots of German economic behaviour.

[ The comments section of Part 1 is now closed. In order to comment, please go to Part 2, “The Anthropology of Financial Crises“. ]


Filed under: Emmanuel Todd, Financial Crises, International Monetary Economics Tagged: current account, Emmanuel Todd, Euro, Eurozone, financial crisis, France, Germany, Pettis

Viewing all articles
Browse latest Browse all 102

Trending Articles